Some day, we will get universal health care with no income tests in America. But first, the Democrats will have to resolve to lead.
This post was published on the now-closed HuffPost Contributor platform. Contributors control their own work and posted freely to our site. If you need to flag this entry as abusive, send us an email.

Senator John McCain’s recuperation from surgery has given Republican Senate leader Mitch McConnell another week or so to round up votes for the latest scheme to repeal the Affordable Care Act. But the week also produces more time for opposition to build.

At this point, it’s hard to imagine how he might assemble 50 votes. Ted Cruz’s idea of allowing barebones policies to count as insurance has only increased opposition, including from the insurance industry itself.

The new, improved Republican health plan has won no converts, and the fence-sitters such as Nevada’s Senator Dean Heller seem dug in. When the Congressional Budget Office calculates the impact, about as many people will likely be projected to lose coverage as in the previous bill — upwards of 20 million.

As a last resort, McConnell has said he will turn to a bipartisan fix in the ACA’s defects. But what would that mean? The defects, from the Democratic perspective, are that ObamaCare covers too little at too high a cost, while most Republicans fault the ACA for covering too much at taxpayer expense.

There is, however, a deeper defect in the entire approach, and that is the ACA’s touching faith in market competition. In theory, having lots of insurers in a given market competing for customers via regulated “exchanges” was supposed to maximize choice, promote innovation, and restrain costs.

This use of markets, however, required a measure of regulation. The ACA specifies required coverage and limits permissible tactics for maximizing profits by gaming the system.

But those fairly modest rules have caused some insurers to pull out of many markets, giving the remaining insurers too much market power, raising premium costs, and often depressing consumer “choice” to one or two insurance companies. That in turn, gives Republicans a nice political target.

In addition, the Republicans’ own efforts to kill the ACA have created uncertainty, causing some insurers to exit the field and increasing costs. It’s awfully hard to see what kind of bipartisan compromise to “improve” the ACA could emerge from this stalemate.

Many Democrats have already started looking beyond the ACA to some form of universal health care. This could take the form of a more robust public option—the idea that every insurance market must have public insurance to compete with private insurance options. This was part of the original ACA design, but was thrown overboard in an effort to pick up necessary votes.

Another idea would be to give people age 50 and over the right to buy into Medicare if that seemed a better deal than the policies on offer. These are the people hit with steeply rising premiums, even under the ACA. My colleague Paul Starr terms this idea “Midlife Medicare.”

Or Democrats could move directly to Medicare for All. This presents difficult transitional problems, since it entails shifting something like a seventh of the entire GDP from a crazy quilt of employer provided plans, self-pays, and fragmented public programs to universal tax-supported coverage.

Regardless of what happens to the Republican effort to kill the Affordable Care Act, in 20 years ObamaCare could well be remembered as a diversion and a distraction. Unlike genuinely public and universal programs such as Social Security and Medicare, the ACA was always a far cry from a true public program.

There are two basic flaws in the approach, which Republicans have exploited, one political and the other economic.

The economic fallacy is that the idea that managed competition ― private for profit insurance plans subject to government rules ― was an efficient road to universal health coverage. This concept, invented by a group of intellectuals and industry people called the Jackson Hole Group, found its way into Bill and Hillary Clinton’s failed 1993 proposal and then into the ACA. It expects too much both of markets and of micro-regulation.

The political problem is that with upwards of 85 percent of Americans already insured at the time the ACA took effect, ObamaCare was always vulnerable as insurance for “Them” at the expense of “Us.” The ACA did bring coverage to nearly half the uninsured, but at great political cost.

In retrospect, it would have been better simply to expand Medicaid as a genuine public program. Yes, Medicaid is substantially for “Them.” But since Medicaid also provides nursing home coverage for the middle class (once they have spent down assets), politically Medicaid is partly bullet-proofed because it is also for “Us.”

As an example of just how stingy U.S. health insurance policy is, consider this. To get nursing home care under Medicaid, you basically have to pauperize yourself first—that’s the practical meaning of “spending down” assets.

By contrast, in Britain, Conservative Prime Minister Theresa May got hammered in the recent election because she proposed that Britons who received nursing home care under the National Health Service repay the government after they die from their estates, with an exemption of the equivalent of $130,000. This was widely ridiculed as a Dementia Tax, and quickly withdrawn. So Brits continue to get all the nursing home care they need, with no income test—and under a conservative government.

Some day, we will get universal health care with no income tests in America. But first, the Democrats will have to resolve to lead.

Robert Kuttner is co-editor of The American Prospect and professor at Brandeis University’s Heller School. His latest book is Debtors’ Prison: The Politics of Austerity Versus Possibility.

Like Robert Kuttner on Facebook.

Follow Robert Kuttner on Twitter

Before You Go

LOADINGERROR LOADING

Popular in the Community

Close

What's Hot